The Yale Law Journal

VOLUME
127
2017-2018
NUMBER
5
March 2018
1106-1447

Dodd-Frank Is a Pigouvian Regulation

Banking LawAdministrative Law

abstract. Almost eight years after the passage of Dodd-Frank, financial institutions remain large, complex, and interconnected. Academics and policymakers across the ideological spectrum largely agree that Dodd-Frank has imposed substantial compliance costs on systematically important financial institutions (SIFIs) without solving the problem that they are too big to fail. This Note argues that Dodd-Frank’s compliance costs have actually served an important regulatory purpose. By analyzing the spinoffs and divestitures that have occurred at eleven SIFIs since Dodd-Frank went into effect in 2010, this Note documents the extent to which the Act’s compliance costs have led SIFIs to shed business lines of their own accord. The data reveal that regulators can adjust Dodd-Frank’s costs in response to the perceived riskiness of specific business units, and that SIFIs can respond to these adjustments by divesting the business lines that caused their compliance costs to increase—that is, SIFIs’ riskiest lines of business. In this way, Dodd-Frank has had an effect analogous to that of a Pigouvian tax—what we call a “Pigouvian regulation.” Furthermore, because Dodd-Frank grants regulators discretion to ramp up (or down) these compliance costs over time, it provides them with powerful tools to incentivize SIFIs to become less systemically important. We therefore conclude that Dodd-Frank’s compliance costs are not a mere ancillary effect of the law, but rather support the Act’s core purpose by empowering regulators to force SIFIs to divest themselves of their riskiest assets. In doing so, regulators can—and have—made financial institutions safer.

author. Aaron M. Levine, Yale Law School J.D. 2017, is an associate at Sullivan & Cromwell LLP. Joshua C. Macey, Yale Law School J.D. 2017, is a law clerk for Judge J. Harvie Wilkinson III. The views and opinions expressed in this Note are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of Sullivan & Cromwell LLP or its clients.

We are deeply grateful for the help we received from friends, mentors, and family in writing this Note. We would also like to thank Samir Doshi, Arjun Ramamurti, Anthony Sampson, Erin van Wesenbeeck, and Kyle Victor for fantastic feedback at numerous stages of the project, and all the editors of the Yale Law Journal for their meticulous editing. We are especially indebted to Jamie Durling and Annika Mizel for extraordinary comments, and to Professors Amy Chua, William Eskridge, Jerry Mashaw, and Jonathan Macey. All mistakes are our own.